So Where Do Good Ideas Come From?

I ran across an outstanding post today by John Battelle reviewing Where Good Ideas Come From: The Natural History of Innovation.by Steven Johnson.

It’s one of my favourite books from the last couple of years, and Battelle does a great job of highlighting the key points in it. He also reminded me of a table that Johnson put in towards the end of the book. It looks at the genesis of what he thought were the most significant ideas of the 19th and 20th centuries. He then assessed whether they were developed in commercial firms or non-commercial organisations, and whether they were generated by individuals or by networks of people.

Here’s the table:

This illustrates several important points:

  • It’s never either/or, it’s both/and. Are individuals or networks more innovative? Networks – there’s plenty of research to back this idea up. Nevertheless, individuals still generate plenty of big ideas. It’s the same with market vs. non-market – lots of great ideas come from both. More come from non-commercial environments.

    It’s really easy to argue black and white statements (“Only small firms innovate!” “No – only big ones do!”). But they’re never true. In order to support innovation, we need to look at these dichotomies and figure out which circumstances favour one approach over the other. And then we need to support both. This is true for market vs. non-market, for individuals vs. networks, for big firms vs. small firms.

    Black and white thinking is dangerous.

  • Networks are a critically important source of great ideas. The lone inventor idea is still with us. Here is what Johnson says about networks:

    Ideas rise in crowds, as Poincaré said. They rise in liquid networks where connection is valued more than protection. So if we want to build environments that generate good ideas—whether those environments are in schools or corporations or governments or our own personal lives—we need to keep that history in mind, and not fall back on the easy assumptions that competitive markets are the only reliable source of good ideas. Yes, the market has been a great engine of innovation. But so has the reef.

    The second part of that quote leads to the next point:

  • Non-market organisations are critical components of the innovation ecosystem. Many of the ideas that led to you being able to read this blog post came from non-market networks – the computer and the internet being chief among them. But just to illustrate the first point, smart phones, which aren’t in the table, came from a market network. Nevertheless, it’s important to understand how crucial non-market organisations are to generating big ideas.
  • Most big ideas get turned into innovations by the market. Here is what Battelle says:

    This doesn’t mean those ideas don’t become the basis for commerce – quite the opposite in fact. But this is a book about how good ideas are created, not how they might be exploited. And we’d be well advised to pay attention to that as we consider how we organize our corporations, our governments, and ourselves – we have some stubborn problems to solve, and we’ll need a lot of good ideas if we’re going to solve them.

    Effectively connecting non-market organisations with market-based firms is one of the most important roles of government. In regions that innovate well, these two sectors interact more effectively than in less innovative regions.

Invention and innovation are two different things. However, we still need to start with a great idea to innovate well. Understanding how good ideas originate is an important part of doing this.

Student and teacher of innovation - University of Queensland Business School - links to academic papers, twitter, and so on can be found here.

Please note: I reserve the right to delete comments that are offensive or off-topic.

2 thoughts on “So Where Do Good Ideas Come From?

  1. That’s a very interesting point, Tim – and one I’ve been thinking about too, recently.

    I think, effectively connecting “idea-validating” and “idea-exploiting” organizations is becoming important. While startups, universities. institutes etc. tend to be stonger in creating innovative ideas, bigger market-based firms are stronger in refining and commerzializing them. However, this kind of “job-sharing” requires considering each other as collaborators, rather than as competitors.

    Bill Buxton nails it in his post “The Long Nose of Innovation”:
    Too often, universities try to contain the results of research in the hope of commercially exploiting the resulting intellectual property. Politicians believe that setting up tech-transfer incubators around universities will bring significant economic gains in the short or mid-term. It could happen. So could winning the lottery. I just wouldn’t count on it. Instead, perhaps we might focus on developing a more balanced approach to innovation—one where at least as much investment and prestige is accorded to those who focus on the process of refinement and augmentation as to those who came up with the initial creation.”
    http://www.businessweek.com/innovate/content/jan2008/id2008012_297369_page_2.htm

    These thoughts might also fit to James Gardner claiming “Breakthroughs don’t pay”:
    http://innovatorinside.com/2011/10/19/breakthroughs-dont-pay/

  2. Idea-validating & idea-exploiting is a very good way to put it Ralph!

    The problem from the university standpoint is that there has been a huge policy shift that has placed an increasingly higher premium on university commercialisation. Despite this, the evidence suggests that this doesn’t help a whole lot. It’s an issue that needs to be looked at…

Comments are closed.