Enough of the Commercialization Gap Myth (Already)!

Saul Eslake is one of Australia’s most respected bank economists. In his tenure as the Chief Economist at the ANZ bank, Eslake’s analysis and forecasts were usually on the mark. He also enjoys a reputation for having a razor-sharp intellect and a balanced attitude to life. We both share a connection to the University of Tasmania, but Eslake grew up in the remote Tasmanian town of Smithton, which probably goes some way to accounting for his grounded approach to life and work.

Fortunately, when he resigned from the ANZ he took a position as a commentator and analyst with a policy think-tank called the Grattan Institute. He has continued to provide inisghts into the challenges of increasing productivity in a mature economy. Crudely speaking, productivity measures the conversion of economic inputs to outputs. Productivity growth is the main driver of sustainable national wealth.

In a recent report, Eslake and Walsh have signalled that Australian productivity is falling. While high prices for coal and iron ore are driving growth in the economy, this is masking some concerning trends in productivity. This matters because a disruption to Chinese commodity consumption, perhaps caused by unforseen political turmoil, would have dire consequences for Australia.

He correctly points out that innovation is a very important driver of productvity. Arresting the decline in productivity means improving national innovation performance. The report also cites education and economic reform as being vital for increasing prodcutivity, but its possible to argue that some of these factors work through innovation. Management skills, in particular, are an important factor in making firms more innovative.

Innovation – the introduction of new goods and services, new ways of producing or distributing existing goods and services, or new ways of managing existing processes for producing or distributing goods and services – has long been recognized as a critically important source of productivity growth.

However, the focus of the report for improving innovation performance is a long way off track.

It is widely recognized that the weakest link in Australia’s innovation chain is the commercialization stage.

One of the dominant innovation myths is that innovation results from the commercialization of an invention – usually a scientific breakthrough. This linear model of innovaiton goes back to the 1950s and despite the mountain of evidence against it, we still see this myth alive and well in public debates and government policy. It’s a problem because it leads to several wrong assumptions about innovation. We’ve written many posts on this blog that I have linked into the following criticisms of these assumptions.

1. Innovation results from the commercialization of R&D. FACTOECD reports show many organizations innovate without any formal R&D.
2. Economies will suffer if they don’t have a high-tech cluster like silicon valley where commercialization can flourish. FACT – High-tech sectors of developed economies directly contribute very little to growth and employment. The international obsession with trying to recreate successful industry clusters is irrational.
4. Commercialization of science will enable the replacement of old industries that don’t grow very much. FACTMany studies show that ‘old’ industries are very innovative and grow rapidly as a consequence.
3. Universities should be compelled to commercialize their research, like US universities. FACT – Every survey of firms in the US, Australia and Europe shows buyers and suppliers as the most important source of innovation. Universities are always a long way down the list. Studies of North-American university commercialization offices show that these are mostly loss-making excercises.

The interesting thing about Eslake and Walsh’s discussion of innovation is that it acknowledges a paper written by some of the best innovation academics from the UK and Australia. This report also criticizes the view of innovation as a linear process where ‘market failure’ results in inventions not being commercialized. Instead, Dodgson et al. talk about the need to create innovation systems. New connections are the source of innovation, not the commercialization of ideas.

In concluding their productivity report, Eslake and Walsh foreshdow a deeper investigation of the innovation dilemma in Australia. A closer reading of Dodgson et al. would be a good start. Forget innovation chains, let’s talk about networks and systems.

Please note: I reserve the right to delete comments that are offensive or off-topic.

4 thoughts on “Enough of the Commercialization Gap Myth (Already)!

  1. John

    A very genuine thank you for taking the time to read our report and to make these comments on it (and also for the kind remarks at the beginning of this post).

    I really appreciate this kind of critical feedback.

    As you note, our report foreshadows a deeper investigation of the innovation process and system in Australia. We would like to do more than simply traipse over old ground, and I hope you will be willing to engage with us as we do. I readily admit that I come to this issue with very little prior knowledge – which also, I’d like to think, means very little pre-judgement or prejudice, apart from what you would expect a former Treasury official (admittedly only a very junior one) to think about suggestions that the whole problem can be solved by bigger tax breaks for R&D.

    As part of our approach we’ll be organization a ’round-table’ on innovation later this year, it would be great if you and Tim can participate.

  2. Saul

    thanks for the note – a very pleasant surprise! The productivity debate needs to be kept alive and your report does makes a real contribution to this issue. Tim and I would be delighted to be part of the Grattan Institute’s round table on innovation. I’ll send you an email.

    John

Comments are closed.